Education, Skills, and the Labour Market
It is undisputed that the human capital of a nation accumulated through schooling and lifelong learning is crucially important to the economy’s innovative capacity and ability to compete in the globalized world of the 21st century. At the individual level, human capital can be regarded as skills that make workers more productive in performing their work tasks and as the knowledge and competencies that enable people to generate and adopt new ideas that spur innovation. At the macroeconomic level, human capital can accelerate economic growth by increasing aggregate productivity and by facilitating the creation and diffusion of new technologies.
One stream of research in this group deals with the formation of skills. The focus is on family background, formal education, and on-the-job training as determinants of skill development. In terms of family influences, we see substantial intergenerational persistence between parents and children in income, educational attainment, and occupational choices. One source of this persistence is the intergenerational transmission of cognitive skills, as we show using unique Dutch data that link comparable measures of math and language skills over generations. However, family circumstances are not “self-inflicted” and are beyond the control of the individual; Nobel laureate James J. Heckman coined them “accident of birth”. Thus, differences in family background and support are a source of inequality – the lack of equality of opportunity. We study the effectiveness of policies to support children and youths from disadvantaged families, in particular, early child care and mentoring programmes. However, one fundamental challenge with formally non-selective programmes such as universal child care is that disadvantaged families are often less able to access and utilize these programmes. In a series of field experiments, we investigate why disadvantaged families are underrepresented in such programmes, focusing on both demand side reasons (e.g., lack of information or difficulties navigating complex application processes) and supply side reasons (e.g., discrimination of educational providers).
Related to our research on economic inequality at the individual level, we also study inequality at the regional level. Regional economic disparities, to a large extent driven by firms located in certain regions, can promote other forms of regional disparities. One such dimension in many western societies is the rise of radical right parties since the late 1980s. We contribute to this discussion by trying to understand the role of firm- und regional-level adjustments to globalization and technological change at the disaggregated European level. Particularly, we study how these significant economic changes affect vote shares of populist and nationalist parties because of the economic hardship caused by these phenomena.
Of particular interest in this research group is the intersection of labour market, education, and innovation research. As technology is changing the tasks workers perform at the job, automating certain tasks and introducing new tasks in which humans have a comparative advantage, the skills required from workers also change. A series of research projects aims at improving our understanding of the interplay between technology, skill supply, and skill demand. For instance, we derive novel measures of worker skills by exploiting the unique setting of the German apprenticeship system, which mandates that the same practical and theoretical skills are developed in a particular apprenticeship regardless of the training location in Germany. Linking these skill measures to rich administrative labour market data, we estimate the returns to various types of skills developed during apprenticeship training, such as cognitive, social, digital, and manual skills. Moreover, the analysis of apprenticeship plan updates will be informative about which types of skills have become more (or less) important over time, and how this interacts with the tasks that new technologies are able to perform. Furthermore, merging workers’ skill supply from apprenticeship plans with firms’ skill demand from online job vacancies allows us to investigate whether returns to skills are systematically higher in firms which require these skills. This will shed light on the complementarities between technologies and skills.
We also investigate the differences in entrepreneurship and business dynamism and their respective contributions to growth between the United States and Germany, particularly focusing on the significance of startups. While startups in the United States are well-known for their innovation and radical advancements, evidence suggests that Germany's innovation is more concentrated within established firms (i.e., incumbents). In a comparative analysis between Germany and the United States, we aim to delve into the preferences of high-skilled individuals for working in startups (vs. incumbents), to better understand the factors influencing startup activity and success in both countries. In addition to the Germany-U.S. comparison, we will also shed light on the question to what extent the relatively low entrepreneurship rate in East Germany can be explained by individuals’ tastes for working in a startup. Starting from the observation that Germany is highly innovative and competitive despite having few startups, we then discuss how the German economy still maintains high levels of innovativeness and competitiveness.
Workpackage 1: (Unequal) Access to Education and the Formation of Skills
Workpackage 2: Returns to Skills
Workpackage 3: Innovation and Business Dynamism in Germany and the United States
Research Cluster
Productivity and InstitutionsYour contact
Refereed Publications
Application Barriers and the Socioeconomic Gap in Child Care Enrollment
in: Journal of the European Economic Association, forthcoming
Abstract
Why are children with lower socioeconomic status (SES) substantially less likely to be enrolled in child care? We study whether barriers in the application process work against lower-SES children — the group known to benefit strongest from child care enrollment. In an RCT in Germany with highly subsidized child care (N = 607), we offer treated families information and personal assistance for applications. We find substantial, equity-enhancing effects of the treatment, closing half of the large SES gap in child care enrollment. Increased enrollment for lower-SES families is likely driven by altered application knowledge and behavior. We discuss scalability of our intervention and derive policy implications for the design of universal child care programs.
Why Is the Roy-Borjas Model Unable to Predict International Migrant Selection on Education? Evidence from Urban and Rural Mexico
in: World Economy, forthcoming
Abstract
<p>The Roy-Borjas model predicts that international migrants are less educated than nonmigrants because the returns to education are generally higher in developing (migrant-sending) than in developed (migrant-receiving) countries. However, empirical evidence often shows the opposite. Using the case of Mexico-U.S. migration, we show that this inconsistency between predictions and empirical evidence can be resolved when the human capital of migrants is assessed using a two-dimensional measure of occupational skills rather than by educational attainment. Thus, focusing on a single skill dimension when investigating migrant selection can lead to misleading conclusions about the underlying economic incentives and behavioral models of migration.</p>
Information about Inequality in Early Child Care Reduces Polarization in Policy Preferences
in: Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, December 2024
Abstract
<p>We investigate public preferences for equity-enhancing policies in access to early child care, using a survey experiment with a representative sample of the German population (n ≈ 4, 800). We observe strong misperceptions about migrant-native inequalities in early child care that vary by respondents’ age and right-wing voting preferences. Randomly providing information about the actual extent of inequalities has a nuanced impact on the support for equity-enhancing policy reforms: it increases support for respondents who initially underestimated these inequalities, and tends to decrease support for those who initially overestimated them. This asymmetric effect leads to a more consensual policy view, substantially decreasing the polarization in policy support between under- and overestimators. Our results suggest that correcting misperceptions can align public policy preferences, potentially leading to less polarized debates about how to address inequalities and discrimination.</p>
Import Shocks and Voting Behavior in Europe Revisited
in: European Journal of Political Economy, June 2024
Abstract
We provide first evidence for the long-run causal impact that Chinese imports to European regions had on voting outcomes and revisit earlier estimates of the short-run impact for a methodological reason. The fringes of the political spectrum gained ground many years after the China shock plateaued and, unlike an earlier study by Colantone and Stanig (2018b), we do not find any robust evidence for a short-run effect on far-right votes. Instead, far-left and populist parties gained in the short run. We identify persistent long-run effects of import shocks on voting. These effects are biased towards populism and, to a lesser extent, to the far-right.
Can Mentoring Alleviate Family Disadvantage in Adolescence? A Field Experiment to Improve Labor-Market Prospects
in: Journal of Political Economy, No. 3, 2024
Abstract
We study a mentoring program that aims to improve the labor-market prospects of school-attending adolescents from disadvantaged families by offering them a university-student mentor. Our RCT investigates program effectiveness on three outcome dimensions that are highly predictive of later labor-market success: math grades, patience/social skills, and labor-market orientation. For low-SES adolescents, the mentoring increases a combined index of the outcomes by over half a standard deviation after one year, with significant increases in each dimension. Part of the treatment effect is mediated by establishing mentors as attachment figures who provide guidance for the future. Effects on grades and labor-market orientation, but not on patience/social skills, persist three years after program start. By that time, the mentoring also improves early realizations of school-to-work transitions for low-SES adolescents. The mentoring is not effective for higher-SES adolescents. The results show that substituting lacking family support by other adults can help disadvantaged children at adolescent age.
Working Papers
Behavioral Barriers and the Socioeconomic Gap in Child Care Enrollment
in: CESifo Working Paper, No. 9282, 2021
Abstract
Children with lower socioeconomic status (SES) tend to benefit more from early child care, but are substantially less likely to be enrolled. We study whether reducing behavioral barriers in the application process increases enrollment in child care for lower-SES children. In our RCT in Germany with highly subsidized child care (n > 600), treated families receive application information and personal assistance for applications. For lower-SES families, the treatment increases child care application rates by 21 pp and enrollment rates by 16 pp. Higher-SES families are not affected by the treatment. Thus, alleviating behavioral barriers closes half of the SES gap in early child care enrollment.
The Effects of Graduating from High School in a Recession: College Investments, Skill Formation, and Labor-Market Outcomes
in: CESifo Working Paper, No. 8252, 2020
Abstract
We investigate the short- and long-term effects of economic conditions at high-school graduation as a source of exogenous variation in the labor-market opportunities of potential college entrants. Exploiting business cycle fluctuations across birth cohorts for 28 developed countries, we find that bad economic conditions at high-school graduation increase college enrollment and graduation. They also affect outcomes in later life, increasing cognitive skills and improving labor-market success. Outcomes are affected only by the economic conditions at high-school graduation, but not by those during earlier or later years. Recessions at high-school graduation narrow the gender gaps in numeracy skills and labor-market success.