Understanding the Great Recession
Mathias Trabandt, Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin S. Eichenbaum
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics,
No. 1,
2015
Abstract
We argue that the vast bulk of movements in aggregate real economic activity during the Great Recession were due to financial frictions. We reach this conclusion by looking through the lens of an estimated New Keynesian model in which firms face moderate degrees of price rigidities, no nominal rigidities in wages, and a binding zero lower bound constraint on the nominal interest rate. Our model does a good job of accounting for the joint behavior of labor and goods markets, as well as inflation, during the Great Recession. According to the model the observed fall in total factor productivity and the rise in the cost of working capital played critical roles in accounting for the small drop in inflation that occurred during the Great Recession.
Read article
Do We Need New Modelling Approaches in Macroeconomics?
Claudia M. Buch, Oliver Holtemöller
Financial Cycles and the Real Economy: Lessons for CESEE Countries,
2014
Abstract
The economic and financial crisis that emerged in 2008 also initiated an intense discussion on macroeconomic research and the role of economists in society. The debate focuses on three main issues. Firstly, it is argued that economists failed to predict the crisis and to design early warning systems. Secondly, it is claimed that economists use models of the macroeconomy which fail to integrate financial markets and which are inadequate to model large economic crises. Thirdly, the issue has been raised that economists invoke unrealistic assumptions concerning human behaviour by assuming that all agents are self-centred, rationally optimizing individuals. In this paper, we focus on the first two issues. Overall, our thrust is that the above statements are a caricature of modern economic theory and empirics. A rich field of research developed already before the crisis and picked up shortcomings of previous models.
Read article
Deutsche Wirtschaft stagniert – Jetzt Wachstumskräfte stärken
Ferdinand Fichtner, Roland Döhrn, Oliver Holtemöller, Timo Wollmershäuser
Wirtschaftsdienst,
No. 10,
2014
Abstract
In ihrem Herbstgutachten 2014 prognostizieren die Institute in der Gemeinschaftsdiagnose einen Anstieg des Bruttoinlandsprodukts (BIP) von 1,3% (68%-Prognoseintervall: 1,1% bis 1,5%) für das Jahr 2014. Für das kommende Jahr erwarten sie einen Anstieg um 1,2%. Vor einem halben Jahr waren noch Veränderungsraten von 1,9% für dieses und 2,0% für kommendes Jahr erwartet worden. Die Änderung der Prognose basiert zum Teil auf einer veränderten Datengrundlage; das Statistische Bundesamt hat im September 2014 die Ergebnisse der Generalrevision der Volkswirtschaftlichen Gesamtrechnungen (VGR) vorgelegt. Wichtiger ist aber, dass seit dem Frühjahr immer mehr Indikatoren auf eine geringere konjunkturelle Dynamik in der zweiten Jahreshälfte hindeuten.
Read article
Forecast Dispersion, Dissenting Votes, and Monetary Policy Preferences of FOMC Members: The Role of Individual Career Characteristics and Political Aspects
Stefan Eichler, Tom Lähner
Public Choice,
No. 3,
2014
Abstract
Using data from 1992 to 2001, we study the impact of members’ economic forecasts on the probability of casting dissenting votes in the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). Employing standard ordered probit techniques, we find that higher individual inflation and real GDP growth forecasts (relative to the committee’s median) significantly increase the probability of dissenting in favor of tighter monetary policy, whereas higher individual unemployment rate forecasts significantly decrease it. Using interaction models, we find that FOMC members with longer careers in government, industry, academia, non-governmental organizations (NGOs), or on the staff of the Board of Governors are more focused on output stabilization, while FOMC members with longer careers in the financial sector or on the staffs of regional Federal Reserve Banks are more focused on inflation stabilization. We also find evidence that politics matters, with Republican appointees being much more focused on inflation stabilization than Democratic appointees. Moreover, during the entire Clinton administration ‘natural’ monetary policy preferences of Bank presidents and Board members for inflation and output stabilization were more pronounced than under periods covering the administrations of both George H.W. Bush and George W. Bush, respectively.
Read article
Warum ist die Wirtschaftsleistung je Einwohner in allen ostdeutschen Ländern ähnlich hoch?
Axel Lindner
Wirtschaft im Wandel,
No. 4,
2014
Abstract
Das IWH veröffentlicht jeden Sommer eine Prognose für Ostdeutschland. Immer häufiger fragen Journalisten, ob nicht die Entwicklung in dem einen oder anderen Bundesland anders ausfallen müsste als im Osten insgesamt. Ist Sachsen nicht wirtschaftlich ein Musterknabe, und hinkt Mecklenburg-Vorpommern nicht oft hinterher? Der empirische Befund ist ein anderer: Trotz aller Unterschiede scheinen sich die Länder in ihrer wirtschaftlichen Leistungsfähigkeit eher anzugleichen. Wies im Jahr 1991 der Spitzenreiter in Ostdeutschland, das Land Brandenburg, noch ein um 18% höheres Bruttoinlandsprodukt je Einwohner auf als das damalige Schlusslicht (Thüringen), beträgt die Differenz gegenwärtig nur noch 6%; der Spitzenreiter ist jetzt tatsächlich Sachsen, und das Schlusslicht ist Mecklenburg-Vorpommern.
Read article
Do We Need New Modelling Approaches in Macroeconomics?
Claudia M. Buch, Oliver Holtemöller
IWH Discussion Papers,
No. 8,
2014
Abstract
The economic and financial crisis that emerged in 2008 also initiated an intense discussion on macroeconomic research and the role of economists in society. The debate focuses on three main issues. Firstly, it is argued that economists failed to predict the crisis and to design early warning systems. Secondly, it is claimed that economists use models of the macroeconomy which fail to integrate financial markets and which are inadequate to model large economic crises. Thirdly, the issue has been raised that economists invoke unrealistic assumptions concerning human behaviour by assuming that all agents are self-centred, rationally optimizing individuals. In this paper, we focus on the first two issues. Overall, our thrust is that the above statements are a caricature of modern economic theory and empirics. A rich field of research developed already before the crisis and picked up shortcomings of previous models.
Read article